Category Archives: LAWS 666 — International Environmental Law

LAWS666 — Unit 9 — Problems and Exercises

Trade & Environment (WTO & GATT Article XX(b)&(g) Exceptions, On-Going Negotiations)

All students should read and answer the Saving Turtles, Indian-Style Problem.

Everyone should read and think about the problem, but we shall appoint a group of students to work and then present to the class the CPO and Sustainability Problem.

Copyright 2020–21 © David Linnan.

LAWS666 — Unit 9 — Background and Issues

Trade & Environment (WTO & GATT Article XX(b)&(g) Exceptions, On-Going Negotiations)

We have already introduced you in a limited fashion to the WTO and the concept of the multilateral trading system in Unit 8. There are at least three things up in the air more generally, however, in the current overlap between international trade and international environmental law. The outlines of the problem become apparent when you look generally at the trade law jurisprudence below addressed to environmental issues.

1/5 The first is that the overlap between trade and the environment issues remains significant, at the same time as the Trump administration apparently drew a hard line on trade during the past 18-24 months. That means that for the first time in 20+ years, the US is clearly not driving the bus on the trade law front within the WTO (because if it is saying it has withdrawn from the Paris Agreement and wants to get out of various trade obligations, while we are still a WTO member, it is harder then to try to steer trade negotiations, also those with environmental implications). So that as a result, following the disavowal of the Paris Agreement, for better or worse, it seems much more likely that the US may encounter trade issues in conjunction with unilateral environmental actions rather than being able to avoid them in steering actual trade law discussions.

2/5 This may or may not change from a US perspective depending upon who wins the November 2020 elections, with two caveats. The first is that the WTO itself is in something of an uproar since its current Director-General Roberto Azevedo, a Brazilian diplomat, decided to leave office a year early, with the result that candidates to be his successor are currently campaigning themselves, and no one is entirely sure what they are telling member countries behind closed doors while campaigning. The second is that, at least as witnessed by WTO website materials, the WTO has made a visible effort in the past 2-3 years to present itself as being supportive on the trade and environment front. This is presumably in response to European and other member countries speaking out in favour of legal engagement with the environment, also at the WTO.

3/5 What do we mean by that? Prior to the Paris Agreement, there was a very active discussion of what were the permissible trade law measures like border tax adjustments to preserve competitiveness based upon ideas like whether it would be lawful to charge differential tariffs based upon differing levels of energy and pollutants in producing, for example, a ton of steel (think carbon tariffs). The idea was that if a developing country used coal to smelt steel and thereby produced much carbon dioxide, plus used arguably more BTUs, that a higher tariff might be levied in a developed country to protect its unilateral adoption of higher environmental standards. It was considered as a strategy for developed countries that wished unilaterally to adopt more “expensive” developed country high pollution abatement and low emissions energy sources (like renewable energy inputs for steel produced from Japan as example), without thereby lessening competitiveness. And you will notice that such a trade law based “carbon tariff” would not be subject to whatever limitations might have been applicable under the Kyoto Protocol or Paris Agreement). So the problem is that as the US considered doing things like reactivating coal in the name of deregulation, it may work for domestically consumed production, but exported production also incorporating things like steel as an intermediate good may be caught up in the net of what were strategies developed to deal with developing country production. So the concern is how to understand the trade law exposure related to environmental actions? This is an issue that presents itself based upon the idea that for economic reasons, you continue to want to export goods regardless of your domestic discussions about environmental actions, etc. So the concept is that no (wo)man is an– economic– island from an environmental perspective, also under modern trade law, as applied.

4/5 The second issue is that the trade and environment overlap has been worked out largely based upon a jurisprudence that we shall cover. It mandates in part how states must rely on what other states may do in terms of certifying production activities (presumably including energy incorporated into goods, etc.). So in the environmental area, when you worry about trade in goods there are actually considerable constraints on unilateral actions. The hidden point there is twofold, first understanding what the restraints are, and secondly, to the extent it does not appear the Trump administration ultimately contemplated withdrawing from the WTO (the Chamber of Commerce folks really would have rebelled at that point), how you think they might come up in US trade dealings? There are technical issues like regulatory equivalence to touch on, but that is a fancy way of saying the extent to which a country may be constrained to accept how others do things to achieve similar environmental goals.

5/5 The third and final issue is that if trade and the environment overlap, how much is a conflict and how much is a felicitous opportunity? (There is actually a Committee on Trade and the Environment within the WTO structure.) The conflict versus opportunity question is largely an exercise in deciding how to deal with issues of regulatory style. The traditional take is that domestic environmental regulation is largely a command and control exercise, when you try to control pollution based upon point source abatement, etc. If you try to do more market-based regulation (carbon taxes to address market failure, etc.), how does this work in a global as opposed to a national market? There are formal discussions of “green” goods and technology in trade law’s long-running Doha Development Round, but momentarily trade law seems again in stasis as the WTO looks for a new Director General, and a lot of countries wait to see what happens in the November 2020 US elections.

Copyright 2020–21 © David Linnan.

Good Cardio Palm Oil Problem

You have been asked by the Indonesian Minister of Trade a question relating to the problem of genetically modified organism (“GMO”) products. Indonesia is a major palm oil producer and exporter. LIPI (the Indonesian equivalent of the NSF) has developed certain strains of GMO palm oil trees adapted to the increasingly hot Indonesian climate (as a result of climate change). There are two strains of these GMO palm oil trees. The first patented strain simply increases productivity in producing 20% more palm oil than existing “ordinary” (meaning non-GMO) trees. The second patented GMO strain produces the so-called “good cardio CPO” which is a healthier kind of crude palm oil with beneficial effects at the whole population level on the incidence of heart disease on those who consume the good cardio CPO as part of their diet.

The Minister is well aware of the very vocal opposition to GMO technology that exists particularly in Europe, but also elsewhere in the world. He is also aware how difficult it would be to sell either the more productive oil palm seed, or the good cardio oil palm seed to tropical agricultural exporters like Brazil, Malaysia, or African countries if simply using the seeds might disqualify their exports to wealthy, industrialized Europe, or most recently to China. They are also aware of the fact that once the oil palm seeds are planted, the trees do not yield any appreciable amount of CPO for three years (and the trees have to be replaced after 25 years, because thereafter their oil production decreases markedly).

Please counsel the Minister in writing an advisory letter first explaining the applicable trade and environmental law framework for GMO products in the export trade, then suggest how best to approach the problem of successfully introducing the more productive GMO palm oil tree seeds, good cardio seeds and CPO into international commerce, and ultimately selling more productive tree and good cardio CPO and related products into the European Union, China and other international markets.

Should you wonder, as indicated by the geography this is another one of those questions originally written for Indonesian law students. I want to see if you and they understand the law, and the advisability of the proposal the same way.

Copyright 2020–21 © David Linnan.

LAWS666 — Unit 8 — Readings and Viewings

Trade/Scientific Risk NTBs & Non-State Aspects (GMOs Plus)

1/3 Read:

a. EC Measures Concerning Meat and Meat Products (Hormones) (aka Beef Hormone Case, WT/DS26/AB/R & WT/DS48/AB/R, January 16, 1998 WTO Appellate Body edited), if you are confused by some of the references you could refer as necessary to the SPS (Sanitary and Phyto-Sanitary) Agreement

b. Addition to the Convention on Biological Diversity, 2000 Cartagena Biosafety Protocol

c. Dolly the Sheep GMO Case Study

Copyright 2020–21 © David Linnan.

LAWS666 — Unit 8 — Problems and Exercises

Trade/Scientific Risk NTBs & Non-State Aspects (GMOs Plus)

1/3 First read the Beef Hormone case, then do the readings and work individually the separate case study on Dolly the Sheep and GMOs, which follows up on the Cartegena Biosafety Protocol.

2/3 Again individually, how could you apply the Beef Hormones decision to GMOs? Is it consistent with the view of GMOs contained in the Cartagena Biosafety Protocol? What accounts for the different perspectives? How does the Beef Hormones decision approach the question of risk and the ability of countries to set domestic food safety (phylosanitary) standards that would tend to exclude GMOs or other products essentially on a health claim? Can governments set health standards to exclude the import of rotten beef? If so, why not allow the exclusion non-organic beef? How should the Cartagena Protocol as multilateral environmental agreement be reconciled with GATT/WTO obligations?

3/3 Everyone should read and think about it it, but we shall appoint a group of students to work on and present in class the Good Cardio Palm Oil Problem.

Copyright 2020–21 © David Linnan.

LAWS666 — Unit 8 — Background and Issues

Trade/Scientific Risk NTBs & Non-State Aspects (GMOs Plus)

We now edge into the overlap between international trade law and international environmental law, to be embraced more directly in Unit 9. The risk assessment area constituting our initial foray emerged in practice from two different directions, namely on the one hand through pressure from the life sciences (the 1990s emergence of cloning and genetic modification technology), and on the other hand through a regulatory focus on how to handle the resulting genetically modified organisms (GMOs) in ordinary commerce. Remember those more expensive food products labelled as non-GMO that you see every day in the grocery store? Presumably there is a market for non-GMO goods as a matter of consumer preference, but what is the basis of that preference?

1/5 By way of background, we should acknowledge differences in terms of the mindset behind international trade law, or at least the multilateral international trading system, compared to international environmental law. Trade law is treaty-based and enjoys the relative luxury for legal purposes of the centralized World Trade Organization or WTO. It traditionally enjoys strong support from the private sector, so Chamber of Commerce-types lines up on a different side. There is basically a very different orientation towards domestic regulation in trade law resulting from its bias against protectionism. Lawyers are always concerned close to the surface in trade law discussions that normal regulatory jurisdiction not be perverted as a means to avoid import competition, as opposed to a relatively more open-minded search in making international environmental law for something approaching any quasi-regulatory, parts per million-style solution to environmental issues (although the Chamber of Commerce-types may complain about the additional costs imposed by environmental regulation). International trade law’s current travails belong in another course (LAWS 665), but the overlap of trade and the environment is also a legal question for us, since they call upon sometimes different, but overlapping treaties and law.

2/5 We are implicitly focused here on the overlap between the WTO’s legal structures for defining permissible regulation chiefly of food safety concerns under Article 20(b) of the 1994 GATT/WTO Agreement and the question of risk in dealing with genetically modified organisms (GMOs) also governed by the 1992 Convention on Biological Diversity (CBD), or more specifically the amendment to the CBD as framework convention known as the 2000 Cartagena Protocol on Biosafety (Cartagena Protocol). The shared issue is how to deal with risk and regulation, but the answers are very different.

In the 1998 WTO Beef Hormone Appellate Panel Proceeding, the body rejected the action and arguments of the European Union to exclude importation of feedlot-raised or industrially produced livestock (beef) because of the related use of veterinary hormones to accelerate the livestock’s growth (meanwhile, growing livestock faster and heavier makes it a more competitive product in meat industry terms). The formal trade law agreements applied included Article 20(b) of the 1994 GATT/WTO Agreement, and its subsidiary Sanitary and Phytosanitary Agreement (the SPS Agreement, basically governing regulation of food safety in detail). The SPS Agreement required a risk assessment supported by science before EU regulations excluding such “hormone beef” from ordinary consumption would be accepted as a legal matter. Think of this as a dispute about whether only (expensive) “Whole Foods-grade organic beef” could be exported to Europe, as opposed to allowing also (much cheaper) “Food Lion-grade conventional beef” could be labelled as such, and also sold into Europe.

3/5 There were diverse candidates regarding the EU’s motives for the challenged regulation rejecting the importation of hormone beef. There were firstly suspicions concerning a desire to support the EU’s Common Agricultural Policy as a necessary political pillar for the EU to function (because the hormone beef might undercut the price of European livestock, which as a general matter were not produced via feedlots or industrial scale farms, and so were less competitive in terms of meat prices). There were also political considerations given that Green parties were in, or verging on entering, governing coalitions in different parts of the EU, but particularly in Germany (and the Greens placed a high political priority in their party platforms on the exclusion of GMO products, essentially for ideological reasons). There were also relatively close in the rearview mirror a series of so-called “mad cow disease” political scandals which undercut ordinary Europeans’ confidence in domestic food safety regulation. The problem was that allegedly for political reasons, various European ministers of agriculture or similar officials denied the existence of infected cattle in the European food supply chain in the 1980s-90s, with the result of a highly publicized series of pitiful deaths of consumers in Europe due to mad cow disease (Creutzfeld Jakobs disease) allegedly caused by their consumption of “mad cow” meat slaughtered in Europe. So European voters doubted whatever their domestic politicians said about food safety (because they thought the politicians’ statements were driven more by their concern for the farm vote). There were numerous politically valid concerns in the EU militating towards exclusion of hormone-treated beef, but the problem was the lack of a scientific basis for its exclusion as required by the WTO’s SPS Agreement.

Meanwhile the WTO dispute resolution body also opined in the Beef Hormones proceeding that as a matter of law, the EU’s position that the Precautionary Principle argued for by some in international environmental law circles as proper approach to risk (reaching outside the SPS Agreement) had not become customary law. So the Europeans were formally required to permit the importation of hormone beef, although they chose instead non-compliance and are still incurring trade sanctions in lieu of compliance, presumably because of the initial domestic political rationales for their exclusionary decision. When challenges to GMO food importation reached the WTO, the Beef Hormones decision and coverage of the SPS Agreement seemingly dictated the outcome. In fact, the EU as a tactical matter refused to process food safety certifications for GMO foods for a number of years, until eventually the “non-processing” was itself challenged as administrative trade decision, and the EU was formally required to admit non-GMO foods. The latest development includes a European challenge to applicability of the SPS Agreement (with its requirement that food regulations have a basis in science) to the regulation of GMO foods, in favor of the Technical Barriers to Trade (TBT) Agreement, which coincidentally does not contemplate the application of science. The long-running trade dispute over GMO foods continues.

4/5 Meanwhile, the CBD emerged alongside the UN Framework Convention on Climate Change (Greenhouse Gas Convention) as the other important international environmental law convention to come out of the1992 Rio UN Convention meeting. Unlike the Greenhouse Gas Convention, however, the US never signed the CBD. The reason the US failed to embrace the CBD largely involves ideological opposition– as with LOS– to the convention’s recognition of an inchoate interest of a member country in any genetic material from said country commercialized in any product (targeting Big Pharma theoretically for royalties or similar fees when marketing a killer drug for the treatment of HIV, derived from a fungus initially gathered by bio-prospectors in the Amazon river basin). (We shall talk in greater detail about the CBD in Unit 14 as the chief treaty to address biodiversity in the modern setting, but for now are more interested in the Cartagena Protocol.) The Cartagena Protocol as amendment to the CBD as framework convention specifically addressed the issue of GMOs, in a practical sense treating them as inherently dangerous and so subject to regulation and exclusion upon notice from any member country, due to a perceived risk that the genetic material might escape into that country’s ordinary environment and wreak havoc by propagating itself through its environment. The easy to understand analogy is that GMOs were subjected by the Cartagena Protocol to the standards for cross-border trafficking in hazardous waste applicable under the Basel Convention, which we study in Unit 12.

5/5 Ask yourself a resulting legal question in the following terms. The US is a member country of the WTO (thus far, and we presumably continue as such as a matter of self-interest). Meanwhile, the US is not a member country of the CBD or Cartagena Protocol, despite the obvious international environmental law interests at stake. However, the US may follow the development of GMO treatment and other concerns as a non-member observer in CBD meetings of the parties to further develop the framework convention (although as a non-member, its opinions may not count for much in CBD member state deliberations). What is the legal treatment the US and its nationals would be subject to or enjoy concerning GMOs? Under the WTO the US and its nationals interested in GMOs are effectively protected by the Beef Hormones case jurisprudence. Meanwhile, under the CBD or Cartagena Protocol GMOs are subject to aggressive regulation as though they constituted hazardous waste. Remember those Vienna Convention treaty rules we studied in Unit 6?

Copyright 2020–21 © David Linnan.

LAWS666 — Fall 2020 Resource List

General Resources

Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change: Created in 1988 by the World Meteorological Organization (WMO) and the United Nations Environment Programme (UNEP), the objective of the IPCC is to provide governments at all levels with scientific information that they can use to develop climate policies.

The IPCC’s Fifth Assessment (2013-2014) is the most recent.
The IPCC’s Sixth Assessment is in process now.

United Nations: Treaties, international agreements, and associated documents. Search template for the UN’s Official Documents System (ODS) accessed through Documents page. ODS contains conference of the parties (COP) documents.

U.S. 4th National Climate Assessment (U.S.), Volume I (2017)
U.S. 4th National Climate Assessment (U.S.), Volume II (2018) – Chapter 19 addresses issues in the Southeastern U.S., including a case study of Charleston’s sea level rise.

Flood Factor: Site enables searching of individual addresses to get an assessment of flood risk. Sponsored by First Street Foundation. First Street Foundation is a non-profit research and technology group defining America’s flood risk. (Get a data set for Charleston by entering Charleston, South Carolina in the search box on the home page.)

World Trade Organization’s Environmental Database: contains all environment-related notifications submitted by WTO members as well as environmental measures and policies mentioned in the Trade Policy Reviews of WTO members.

Thomas Cooper Databases: Access from Thomas Cooper’s database page.

GreenFILE: The Thomas Cooper Library does not have a database specifically dedicated to international environmental law, but GreenFILE recognizes “international environmental law” as a subject term. Best research strategy: Select the GreenFILE database from Cooper’s database page. When you get the search template, choose “subject terms” from the “Select a Field” dropdown menu and type “international environmental law” into the accompanying search box. Use other Boolean fields if needed. Use options in left-hand sidebar to filter results.

Agricultural and Environmental Sciences Collection: Best search strategy: Access database and type in the search box (example: international climate). The search engine’s auto-complete feature will populate a number of choices, so you can select one if you find one you like, but you can also run a keyword search without selecting any of the suggested choices. Use options in left-hand sidebar to filter results. Note that the results in this database contain dissertations. Warning: this database is not guaranteed to offer a full-text format for every result discovered.

ASFA: Aquatic Sciences and Fisheries Abstracts: includes environmental law on water environments. Note that this database primarily contains abstracts, but the records frequently lead to pdfs of original documents.

Jstor: archive of scholarly articles from numerous fields of study. Access through the law library’s electronic resource link or from Thomas Cooper’s database page.

Research Guide: Environmental issues frequently overlap with business and economic issues. Thomas Cooper Library offers a research guide to international business & statistics – free web resources, Cooper databases for international business, brief instructions on navigating the databases

Bibliographies

Bibliographies, although they become outdated fairly quickly, are good starting points to use in finding resources. Bibliographies will give you listings of resources on a given topic. If they have become outdated, you can check the catalog for more current editions of the resources listed. You can search for bibliographies in the USC Libraries catalog. In the search bar at the top of the page, type: bibliography climate change. Restrict the date if you only want current entries.

Many of these resources are online, and most of the physical volumes will be located outside of the law library. We share our new catalog system with the entire borrowing consortium of SC academic libraries, so to filter results by library use the “Library” filter on the left-hand sidebar of your catalog results.

Examples:

Global climate change pathfinder: a guide to information sources
Print resource available at Thomas Cooper Library, Call Number QC981.8 .C5 P54 1992

VULNERABILITY ASSESSMENT METHODOLOGIES: AN ANNOTATED BIBLIOGRAPHY FOR CLIMATE CHANGE AND THE FISHERIES AND AQUACULTURE SECTOR
William Barsley ; Cassandra De Young ; Cécile Brugère
FAO fisheries and aquaculture circular, 2013-01-01 (1083), p.I
… PREPARATION OF THIS DOCUMENT This circular contains a comprehensive annotated bibliography of vulnerability methodologies specific to climate change…(online resource)

Global sea level rise scenarios for the United States National Climate Assessment
Parris, Adam, author.; United States. National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration. Climate Program Office, issuing body.
2012 (online resource – pdf)

If you don’t find anything you like in the catalog, a Google search will also turn up bibliographies. Publishers, government agencies, and academic institutions might be the providers. Suggested search: bibliography climate change

Examples:

Penn State: https://sites.psu.edu/helpclimatechange/bibliography/

NOAA: https://repository.library.noaa.gov/view/noaa/1369

NYU: https://www.nyulawglobal.org/globalex/Climate_Change_Bibliography1.html

Law-Related Resources

Hein Online: Scholarly archive of pdf documents; contains databases for international treaties and agreements, as well as UN documents collection. Also contains documents related to international environmental law. Best search strategy: conduct a catalog search within Hein for international environmental.

Access through the law library’s electronic resource link or from Thomas Cooper’s database page.

American Society of International Law (ASIL): Good collection of general information; some access restricted to members. Topics section offers pages on International Law and Climate Change (currently under development) and Environment, Health, Science, & Technology, and International Economics; contains links to agreements and reports.

Lexis: Practice Area on International Law (no practice area specifically for international environmental law).

Congressional Research Service (CRS): Search for “climate change” in the search box on the homepage. Results filtered on the left-hand sidebar

House of Representatives: Get hearings on climate change. From search bar in upper right of homepage, type: hearing climate change (works on any other keyword, such as sustainability)

ProQuest Congressional: Research tool accessed through the law library’s electronic resources page. Access to congressional documents and activity, including bills, committee reports, transcripts of testimony from congressional hearings, and debates and statements from members of Congress. Full-text information can be retrieved using search terms or document numbers. Most productive search strategy to get hearings on the Fourth National Climate Assessment: The ProQuest Congressional homepage will likely default to “Congressional Publications.” Accept this default and use the link for the “Advanced” search. In the “Content Types” on the left-hand sidebar, uncheck everything but Hearings, CRS Reports, and House and Senate Documents/Reports. In the search box in the upper middle of the screen, type “Fourth National Climate Assessment” (typing 4th doesn’t work as well). Using the dropdown for “in” change the location to Anywhere. You won’t need to set the date because the Fourth National Climate Assessment was done in 2018, so won’t come up in other time frames.

State or Municipal Climate Change Lawsuits

On September 9, 2020, the City of Charleston filed a lawsuit against 24 fossil fuel corporations over issues related to climate change.  Other municipalities and states have filed their own climate change suits. The Sabin Center for Climate Change Law at Columbia Law maintains a page that tracks these cases.  The site also offers a portal to non-US climate litigation.  Information on the recent US state/city lawsuits can be found in the link for “Common Law Claims” in the portal for U.S. Climate Change Litigation.

Michael Burger, Executive Director of the Sabin Center, writes extensively on climate change law.  You can find a list of his selected publications here.  If you can’t link directly to an article from this list, use the citation information to search in the online database service of your choice.  If that doesn’t get you access to the article, contact a member of the reference team in your law library for help.

Sher Edling LLP is the law firm that represents the plaintiffs in several of these climate change actions by states or municipalities.  The firm has posted a collection of documents related to this litigation.

The US Energy Information Administration has created a profile for South Carolina (and the other states).  This profile provides data on energy use, resources, and industry in the state.

The EPA provides data on greenhouse gas emissions from the transportation sector, and has created a portal containing information about greenhouse gases and emissions in the U.S.

Surging Seas Risk Finder:  maintained by the non-profit Climate Central, this site offers data and mapping tools that visualize an area’s flood risk, social vulnerability, population, income, and other variables.  Get data and map indicators for Charleston by entering the city’s name in the search box on the landing page.

City-data.com:  The site includes interactive data tools that let you mix and match numerous variables and generate online reports, as well as provides pre-made data sets if you enter a location (City of Charleston, Charleston County).

Research Guide:  Thomas Cooper offers a guide on geospacial and climate data. Geospatial means relating to or denoting data that is associated with a particular location (like Charleston, SC).

Journal Article:  Shana Jones, Thomas Ruppert, Erin L. Deady, Heather Payne, J. Scott Pippin, & Ling-Yee Huang, Jason M. Evans, Roads to Nowhere in Four States: State and Local Governments in the Atlantic Southeast Facing Sea-Level Rise, 44 Colum. J. Envtl. L. 67, 70 (2019)

This Article uses roads as a case study to explore how sea-level rise is altering planning, maintenance, and funding for public infrastructure.  South Carolina is one of the four states that were studied for the article.  Article is available on Westlaw, Lexis, and Hein Online.

Think Tanks: Websites and Resources: offer research data, blogs, articles, videos, commentary, and analysis. These are largely economically oriented research operations, engaged more in popularization rather than basic research, so make your own decisions about word-searching the environment versus climate change, etc.

Brookings Institute: “The Brookings Institution is a nonprofit public policy organization based in Washington, DC. Our mission is to conduct in-depth research that leads to new ideas for solving problems facing society at the local, national and global level.” Website offers links for global development and international affairs.

Center for Strategic and International Studies: “The Center for Strategic and International Studies (CSIS) is a bipartisan, nonprofit policy research organization dedicated to advancing practical ideas to address the world’s greatest challenges.”

American Enterprise Institute: “The American Enterprise Institute is a public policy think tank dedicated to defending human dignity, expanding human potential, and building a freer and safer world.”

The Cato Institute: “The Cato Institute is a public policy research organization — a think tank — dedicated to the principles of individual liberty, limited government, free markets, and peace. Its scholars and analysts conduct independent, nonpartisan research on a wide range of policy issues.”

Peterson Institute for International Economics: “The Peterson Institute for International Economics (PIIE) is an independent nonprofit, nonpartisan research organization dedicated to strengthening prosperity and human welfare in the global economy through expert analysis and practical policy solutions.” Offers research, blogs, news

Copyright 2020–21 © David Linnan.

LAWS666 — Unit 7 — Readings and Viewings

Issues with Markets, Distributive Justice & Agency Problems in International Environmental Law (Hidden Economics & Environmental Justice)

1/3 Read

a. The Distributive Effects of Economic Instruments for Environmental Policy. Pp. 39-62 (OECD 1994)

b. Eskimo Whaling Problem

c. Japan Whaling Association website cultural arguments on the permissibility of whale catching by modern cultures

2/3 For those with no prior familiarity with Charleston’s recent US Army Corps of Engineers Surge Barrier Study, take a look at the Corps’ website summarizing the recently completed Charleston Coastal Flood Risk Management Study.

3/3 Read as counterpoint Robinson, “Commentary: Army Corp’s plan for Charleston is worse than doing nothing at all” (Post & Courier 08/12/20).

Copyright 2020–21 © David Linnan.

LAWS666 — Unit 7 — Problems and Exercises

Issues with Markets, Distributive Justice & Agency Problems in International Environmental Law (Hidden Economics & Environmental Justice)

1/4 Regarding the OECD excerpted publication on the distributive effects of policy instruments, how do you understand the explanation that economic policy instruments commonly considered to be neutral in effect do have distributive consequences within a single country or location? How do the distributive consequences work, and why worry about the effects anyway, as long as overall efficiency is served? Is there any difference here between purely domestic versus international schemes employing economic policy instruments? For example, consider the various carbon offset arrangements in which developed countries may fund projects reducing net carbon emissions, etc. in developing countries, as a way to satisfy their own, higher obligations to reduce carbon emissions.

2/4 If you look closely at the Eskimo Whale Hunting case and the Japan Whaling Association website, you notice that both implicitly make cultural arguments concerning the environment (remember the Freeport McMoran complaint and the cultural genocide count), but are not entirely able to pull them off. The former tries to make the argument that modern Inuit oil workers are engaged in cultural activities pursuing endangered species of whales as the exercise of indigenous rights following in their grandfathers’ footsteps, but they come off more like Civil War reenactors because they have entered the modern economy already. In the name of Japanese culture, the later seemingly condones commercial whaling dressed up as scientific research, which argument other countries think does not even pass the straight face test. What is the cautionary lesson there for broad application of environmental or distributive justice argumentation based upon claims about present or past practices carried forward to the present?

3/4 Agency problems are something law students typically have already encountered no later than courses like business corporations law, presenting problem of an agent formally acting on behalf of a principal (theoretically with the principal’s best interests at heart), but in the meantime agents more often serve their own personal interests (think of CEOs effectively setting their salaries). The classic problem is that agents often have superior knowledge of facts on the ground compared to a principal, and so their performance is very difficult to monitor. But if the principal improves his knowledge and monitors the agent ever more closely, the whole process simply becomes too time-consuming. Such problems are endemic in the context of recent international environmental law with heavy involvement of non-governmental organizations or NGOs over governments. Who represents the ordinary citizen better, and why, a single-issue, specialized non-governmental organization, or ordinary government responsible generally for public welfare? Nonetheless, agency issues are typically ignored with NGOs, perhaps as a result of their customary non-profit status. And particularly in areas like climate change, where there may be a variety of competing interests and parties, and pressures to change very basic economic arrangements (for example, decarbonization of the economy), it is difficult to make informed choices even without interposing potentially conflicted agents. Thus, this is as much as anything else a sensitization exercise, to engender consciousness of the conflicts.  So please work through on an individual basis the John Q Public Problem.

4/4 Meanwhile, distributive justice concerns are not solely the province of international environmental law, but they are unavoidable as soon as challenges like climate change are recognized as requiring broad evolution in economic structures themselves (e.g., decarbonization of the economy), at the same time as the lasting conflict is recognized between different groups of states who may place more emphasis on improving or guarding their economic and social circumstances in the midst of change.  The descriptives of developing and industrialized states captures the tension, which also accounts for the idea that certain areas of law like international trade law and international environmental law are as much growing together as conflicting in certain areas.  We borrow border adjustment tariffs or taxes as one current area of technical concern from international trade law, and overlapping concerns it raises in international environmental law, by having a student group work on the Border Adjustment Taxes (Environmental Tariffs) Problem as well as students groups working over the balance of the semester generally on (not very simple) current domestic Charleston sea level rise issues, to get a sense for how hard it is to make a variety of decisions implicating distributive justice even in the purely domestic setting via the Charleston Problem.

Copyright 2020–21 © David Linnan.

John Q. Public Problem

This problem addresses the differing perspectives and motivations of non-governmental organizations (“NGOs”) and governments (“Governments”) as they strive formally to represent the public in international environmental matters. The method of approach is borrowed from economics (mostly public choice or game theory, but unless you are eager to bone up on your mathematics we shall spare you a more formal introduction to the methodologies). You might want to look at the article Hazard & Kunreuther, Protecting the Environment: Finding the Balance Between Delaney and Free Play, 18 University of Pennsylvania Journal of International Economic Law 487 (1997). This article employs a bit of agency and informational analysis in an institutional setting to look at environmental risks under different institutional arrangements. The point in looking at the article is simply to inform yourself about how a non-mathematical treatment of these kind of issues might look.

We cast the problem in the following terms. The average member of the public (“John Q. Public”) may be concerned about the environment in a general sense, but is not well informed and has a variety of competing concerns. John Q. Public works in an industry “threatened” by international trade (meaning the foreigners are so much more efficient producers of his industry’s products that they can supply them more cheaply to Cascadia’s consumers). In economist’s terms, John Q. Public is a “principal” suffering from a lack of information. We stipulate that there will be permanent assymetries of information concerning the environment because of a lack of time, education, or inclination, so John Q. Public will never be able to match the access to information of “agents” representing him as the principal on environmental matters.

We envision three “agents” competing to represent John Q. Public in the environmental area. In economist’s terms, the problem with agents is that they formally represent principals but in fact have their own motivations. Thus, there is always a risk that agents will take actions formally on a principal’s behalf which in fact serve the agent’s own personal ends. In theory principals may monitor agents to ensure their faithful representation of principal interests. There are two problems with the monitoring idea. First, monitoring is a relatively high cost proposition in terms of John Q. Public’s time and effort. Ultimately, you might spend so much time monitoring that it would be cheaper to do something yourself in lieu of appointing an agent. Second, monitoring assumes development of information. We start with the assumption that, because of assymetries of information, John Q. Public’s agent for the environment will always be better informed on the pros and cons of environmental matters than he. Thus, monitoring is ultimately ineffective in this case.

We now turn to which agents might represent John Q. Public. The first agent is an environmental NGO entitled “Orangesegment.” Orangesegment is an organization of dedicated political activists, scientists and economists nobly and single-mindedly pursuing preservation of the environment. Orangesegment is well-informed about the environment, but suffers as an agent from the motivational conflict that the environment is all it cares about. Orangesegment (or at least its more vocal members) seems to lie just this side of deep ecology on the spectrum of environmental organizations. John Q. Public is not a member of Orangesegment, but he listens to their message on environmental matters like any other member of his media-cocooned society.

The second agent is Government, which we stipulate controls the country (“Cascadia”) where John Q. Public lives. Government is well-informed about the environment given expertise in its environmental regulatory agency, but presumably suffers as an agent from the motivational conflict that it wishes to continue to represent John Q. Public (the incumbent effect) at the same time that it must satisfy competing demands (unlike Orangesegment, Government is not singleminded in its pursuit of the environment). As a loyal citizen of Cascadia, John Q. Public thinks that Government sometimes does stupid things but normally has his best interests at heart.

The third agent is Cascadia’s society for the prevention of cruelty to animals (“CSPCA”). CSPCA is an organization of dedicated animal lovers, veterinarians and little old lady voters nobly and single-mindedly pursuing the humane treatment of animals. CSPCA is well-informed about pets and, to a lesser extent, about the whole animal kingdom from a conservationist point of view. However, its main concern is for domestic animals. In environmental terms, CSPCA is probably best understood as a sentimentalist’s more traditional conservation organization (at least for land mammals). Incidentally, John Q. Public owns a cat named Minette and is a member of CSPCA.

A question has arisen concerning a new draft international convention to save the whales (“Cetacean II”). The original international convention to save the whales (“Cetacean I”) entered international law years ago and represented the standard mish-mash environmental treaty under which nations undertook a obligation to study the alarming decline in the worldwide whale population without really agreeing to any binding obligations. Cascadia was a member to Cetacean I despite the fact that it lost its whaling industry with the demise of the sailing ship.

The country of Asiana is also a signatory to Cetacean I, but has both an active whaling fleet and a population with a taste for whale meat as a traditional delicacy of Asiana cuisine (so highly thought of that consuming whale meat is the culturally significant high point of traditional Asiana wedding banquets). Asiana, which enjoys mutually beneficial trade and security arrangements with Cascadia, is hesitant about Cetacean II precisely because it goes beyond Cetacean I to propose a ban on the taking of whales. Traditionalists decry Cetacean II’s absolute ban on whale hunting as anti-family values, reasoning that disturbing Asiana’s traditional wedding customs strikes yet another blow against a crucial social institution under pressure. Incidentally, Asiana is one of the countries exporting to Cascadia goods in competition with the industry in which John Q. Public works.

Orangesegment is engaged in an all-out lobbying and protest campaign in support of Cetacean II, which is in an advanced stage of negotiations. Cascadia’s Government might favor Cetacean II in the abstract, but is hesitant to push Asiana too hard (because of concerns how that might affect the trade and security arrangements). CSPCA as a conservationist organization is ambivalent about Cetacean II, both because its true focus is on land animal pets and because whale meat is a major component of catfood. In fact, its little-old-lady board of directors is launching a letter-writing campaign for CSPCA’s members to support “save the kittie[s’ food]” by keeping Cascadia out of Cetacean II. Thus, the three potential agents represent three levels of engagement pro and con in the adoption fight for Cetacean II.

Analyze the dynamics of Orangesegment, Government and CSPCA competing as agent to represent John Q. Public as principal to resolve the issue whether Cascadia should become, or pressure other countries to become, a party to Cetacean II (i.e., abandon the taking of whales). Is the resolution really driven by information assymetries or by the competing agents’ own “motives” even when they agitate to act for John Q. Public? What is the position of NGOs versus Governments, which traditionally enjoy a legal monoploy representing their citizens in international legal affairs (i.e., deciding whether or not to enter into a treaty)? Should a Governments’ position invariably take precedence over an NGOs’ position and, if so, why?

Is the right approach in general terms to think about all of these actors as John Q. Public’s agents, or is Cascadia as state the true principal rather than John Q. Public as individual? How would you relate the distinction in structural terms to the international law system to distinguish the traditional view of international law as law between states as opposed to current views of individuals with direct human rights or similar claims? How do you apply substantive international law like views of legal personality on top of the agency/informational access analysis to the three actors? What are the underlying assumptions of the three actors about the international law system, in terms of legal, governmental and democratic elements? We shall approach these questions via role-playing exercise in class.

Copyright 2020–21 © David Linnan.